UNUnited Nations Economic Commission for Europe

Press Releases 2000

[Index]      

UNECE CONVENES SPRING SEMINAR WITH DISCUSSION OF MARKET INSTITUTIONS AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE

Panel Discussions Held on Public and Corporate Governance
and Institutional Change and Economic Performance in Transition Economies

 Geneva, 7 May 2001

The United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE) opened its annual spring seminar this morning with panel discussions focusing on the topic of "market institutions and economic performance". Most of the discussion focused on the economies of eastern Europe and the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS).Two panel debates were held based on papers submitted by William Lazonick of the University of Massachusetts at Lowell (United States of America) and the European Institute of Business Administration (INSEAD); and by Paul Hare of Heriot-Watt University of Edinburgh.Introducing his paper, entitled "Public and corporate governance: The institutional foundations of the market economy", Mr. Lazonick said among other things that what was needed to spur economic development in the transition economies was an effective theory of innovation -- that it was important to understand and apply measures that enabled new ventures to become going concerns that employed many people and positively affected economies.Serving as panellists for the debate on Mr. Lazonick's paper were Victor Polterovich of the Central Economics and Mathematics Institute of Moscow, and Eugen Jurzyca of the Institute for Economic and Social Reforms of Bratislava (Slovakia).Mr. Hare noted in the introduction to his paper, entitled "Institutional change and economic performance in the transition economies", that the transition process from its beginning in 1990-91 had run into mistakes and misjudgements, such as the emphasis on privatizing state-owned enterprises rapidly, and on creating institutions for doing that, rather than focusing on creating new enterprises from scratch, and creating institutions that would help that process along. He said it also was clear that the delicate and complicated process of encouraging economic growth under fledgling market economies required viable and established nation States -- which hadn't always been the case in transition regions -- and required changing the behaviour of enterprises.Serving as panellists on Mr. Hare's paper were Danica Popovic of Belgrade University and Laszlo Csaba of Central European University of Budapest.The morning meeting began with welcoming remarks by Danuta Hübner, Executive Secretary of the UNECE, who said among other things that in understanding developments in the region it was useful not only to know the rules of the game but the players; and from Paul Rayment, Director of the Economic Analysis Division of UNECE, who served as Chairman of the session.The UNECE Spring Seminar will reconvene at 3 p.m. for panel discussions on the topic of "tackling institutional failure".

Introduction

DANUTA HÜBNER, Executive Secretary of the Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE), said among other things that in understanding developments in the region it was useful not only to know the rules of the game but the players -- the governments, the businesses and other decision-makers and the social and cultural backgrounds from which they came. Growth in Europe was necessary, and everyone knew at this point how high the cost could be of institutional failure; institutional frameworks could provide stability and continuity, but that was not in itself sufficient for growth; what was needed was institutional change; the highest payoffs came from effective behaviour within institutional frameworks that allowed sustainable change that enabled business to thrive.The revolution of 1989 had destroyed a great deal of the institutional frameworks in what were now known as transition economies, Ms. Hübner said; rebuilding them on market models had been slow and difficult. The hope that such a transformation could be achieved quickly had not been borne out. Merely copying institutions from market economies wasn't enough; what was required was a process that established effective institutions taking into account the cultures and histories of the countries involved, and the careful application of incentives that encouraged effective market behaviour and acted to prevent corruption and the sort of manipulation that only served the aims of certain vested interests. Ms. Hübner said she hoped that during today's discussion everyone would learn how to get started -- would learn what was the minimum package of reforms necessary to encourage and convince enterprises and investors that reform was under way and to give them confidence that it would continue.PAUL RAYMENT, Director of the Economic Analysis Division of UNECE, said the day's schedule had been clearly outlined. The topics were broad ones and couldn't be covered extensively in one day, but certainly a basic review could be made based on the four excellent papers before the session.

Panel discussion on public and corporate governance

WILLIAM LAZONICK, of the University of Massachusetts at Lowell (United States of America) and the European Institute of Business Administration (INSEAD), introducing his paper, said fifteen or twenty years ago there was still a debate going on over whether the market or the "plan" had to be in place to get a viable economy operating. The message that had been going out from the United States in recent years was that in the age of globalization a critical factor was the need to encourage entrepreneurship. How did new ventures become going concerns that employed many people and positively affected economies? For individuals, obviously, market economies had advantages and were nice places to live -- when they worked well. But his opinion was that such markets were the result rather than the cause of economic development; there was a lot of debate among economists about market imperfections and market failure, but his problem with that was that the benchmark for such talk was a perfect market economy that didn't exist and didn't in any case offer a theory of market development. The question was how did these markets get started?What you needed was a theory of innovation, Mr. Lazonick said, and to do that you had to focus on the characteristics of successful innovation, which according to Mary O'Sullivan were collective, cumulative, and uncertain. Resources had to be allocated in keeping with those characteristics, and in classic situations that often was not the case. Among the social conditions of innovative enterprises were organizational integration, financial commitment and strategic control. Financial commitment of a certain kind was critical -- money had to be allocated to sustain the cumulative innovation process until it could generate financial returns; in other words investment had to be dependable. Organizational control, not market control, seemed to be central to the development of a market economy; and labour and capital mobility only generated development if innovative enterprises and developmental States could manage the markets so that resource allocation was organizational, developmental and strategic.VICTOR POLTEROVICH, of the Central Economics and Mathematics Institute of Moscow, said he would have preferred a more positive evaluation of neo-classical economics. That school of economics also had a theory of innovation based on macro- and microeconomic models; these were based on technological progress and noted that such progress or innovation allowed a particular enterprise to have a brief monopoly on the product that resulted. Neo-classical theory already contained certain important components for the innovative process, therefore. There also had to be effective strategic interactions between owners, operators, and employees to foster innovative behaviour. And there had to be better explanations of the macro- and micro-economic factors involved in innovation.A major mistake in the transition economies had been to place too much emphasis on privatization per se, Mr. Polterovich said; privatized enterprises in the former Soviet Union hadn't necessarily done better than State-managed institutions; what mattered was to get effective structure and effective frameworks established; privatization without that was not going to work very well. Also, institutional "traps" had to be avoided -- such as corruption -- or the economic backwardness of a State could be permanent. Avoiding traps and getting out of them required among other things effective and honest Government; if that did not happen, business development and investment were not stimulated. The State had to promote growth through balanced and wise policies. It further was necessary to learn how to repair the damage done by previous economic cultures that hadn't worked well and were not disposed to deal effectively with market economies; in the Soviet Union there had been, for example, a culture of paternalism and dependence. To develop innovation and thriving markets it was necessary to take into account the cultures of the countries concerned.EUGEN JURZYCA, of the Institute for Economic and Social Reforms of Bratislava, said Mr. Lazonick's paper was a criticism of mainstream economics and raised a topic that could fill year's discussion, let alone ten minutes' worth. He liked the paper because it was provocative and refreshing. The "market" had won over the "plan" as the best way for organizing and running societies, but it was true that markets had characteristics of inequality and instability, and these had to be coped with. The claim that the more perfect the market, the better performing the economy was not necessarily true. In some transition countries, it had to be noted, the natural development toward better market systems had been broken, and the question was what to do and how to respond. The theory of innovative enterprise needed to be developed much more extensively than it had been to date. He wasn't sure the short-term examples used in the paper would necessarily bear out in the long-term, and he wasn't sure if it was true across the board that countries with higher levels of economic freedom were marked by greater inequality; some research had shown that the factors weren't necessarily related.It was very difficult to recognize an original cause of economic growth in many cases, Mr. Jurzyca said; one probably had to look at other sciences than economics for contributing factors, and at different things than merely organizational or market arrangements. One effective approach for innovation appeared to be the Silicon Valley model, with its combination of venture capitalists and innovative enterprises.A number of remarks were offered from the floor. Among other things, speakers asked for further suggestions and advice on macroeconomic regulation in transition countries that would encourage growth and innovation; asked how, in terms of policy prescriptions, the findings of Mr. Lazonick's paper could be applied; questioned whether, in the case of the former Soviet Union, for example, more planning rather than less was needed for setting up an effective and stable economy; and said the paper seemed to give insufficient importance to basic economic theory developed over the past 200 years.

Mr. Lazonick, responding to these remarks, said among other things that he certainly did not mean to say that economic theory wasn't important; on the other hand, a lot of effective theory had been ignored or had gone unapplied as a system of thought -- one got models that didn't go anywhere or theories that didn't get applied to reality. Many economists, in fact, used theory as a way of ignoring reality. Theories had to be integrated and applied to a "reality" that was constantly changing. He felt it was important that it be understood that market forces had to be regulated -- as markets developed and became more active and powerful, regulation became necessary. Hence you might as well say that at the outset. As an economist you couldn't really understand the world without also, in a sense, being a sociologist and taking history and culture into account.

 Panel discussion on institutional change and economic performance in transition economiesPAUL HARE, of Heriot-Watt University of Edinburgh, introducing his paper, said among other things that the transition process from its beginning in 1990-91 had run into mistakes and misjudgements, such as the emphasis on privatizing state-owned enterprises rapidly -- and on creating institutions for doing that -- rather than focusing on creating new enterprises from scratch, and creating institutions that would help that process. Also it had been found that carrying out serious economic and institutional reform couldn't occur effectively without established nation States, and a number of governments among the transition economies had not been fully established and had gone through changes since the transition process had begun. It was further clear that some Governments had not necessarily been committed to establishing market economies, and as a result the extensive and far-reaching reforms necessary had not been effectively undertaken.There were different theories and definitions that could be employed in deciding which sorts of institution were helpful for supporting well-functioning market economies, Mr. Hare said, and choices had to be made among them and among the emphases to be given to different institutions that would govern such economic functions as private property rights and contracts; financial markets; labour markets; and social concerns and safety nets. All of this was complicated by the fact that some of the institutions might not function well or not even be in existence, and the gaps had to be filled in other ways, such as through the private sector. Evidence suggested that some countries had enjoyed earlier and more sustained recovery from post-communist recession as a result of earlier and more effective macroeconomic stabilization and greater commitment to market-oriented reforms, including institutional reforms. A key factor in improving economic performance obviously consisted in changing the behaviour of enterprises; States must effectively address the matter of how to encourage development of new enterprises and how to help those that were potentially viable but momentarily struggling.DANICA POPOVIC, of Belgrade University, said she wondered what was the driving force for creating institutions? And was creating such institutions the new Holy Grail, and was everyone going to stick with this approach? One mistake at the beginning of transition process had been the obsession with speed: effective transition wasn't a horse race; what was important was to think clearly and to act deliberately and to establish well-designed institutions. Private enforcement of law was a point dealt with by the paper, but the topic of excessive bureaucratic power, often corrupt or even run by mafias, was another telling matter -- in Russia and in Yugoslavia, the problem wasn't lack of institutions but corrupt institutions. "Moderate" competition was recommended in the paper to enable enterprises to be created and to survive their initial difficulties, but she wondered, among other things, how long this moderate competition should last.It was clear that effective economic growth wasn't going to be fuelled by foreign direct investment (FDI) alone or especially; and the argument of transition countries that they couldn't grow on their own savings because they were too poor should not be encouraged or repeated, Ms. Popovic said. They had to find a way to sustain growth from internal resources. It was also clear that these countries had to find a way to stimulate and sustain internal consumption.LASZLO CSABA, of Central European University of Budapest, said among other things that it was important to create a synthesis between policies and institutions -- to look at them as unit rather than getting into chicken-and-egg discussions about which came first or was more important. Similarly one had to look at both public and private institutions as neither good nor bad or as one being better than the other but at making these institutions fair and effective. Very often, when one talked about market failure the root cause was State failure, which required States to help the markets through more State intervention, which often meant further ineffective involvement which made things worse.Mr. Csaba asked about the "vicious circle" scenarios that had occurred in some transition countries -- what caused them and what one did about them. He agreed that FDI should not be regarded as something that would save or sustain transition economies; it rather could work as a pacemaker for a while, allowing enterprises to learn the new market culture so that they could function effectively and hold their own based on domestic investment and consumption. What was wanted was somehow to get into a virtuous circle, such as was now being seen in Hungary and Poland. Could societies learn, and how? There had to be at least a limited ability for them to learn, especially from their own mistakes, so as to avoid a stagnating situation and an atmosphere of gloom such as one now found in some places in Africa.Delegates offering remarks from the floor said, among other things, that the problem in many countries wasn't a lack of institutions but incorrect functioning of institutions, and asked what could be done to correct their operations, given that States had created and supported such institutions; said more understanding was needed of why market regulation by Governments had failed in some countries, especially Russia, leading to so-far failed transitions; contended that all the emphasis on the importance of domestic saving in transition countries didn't appear to be borne out elsewhere in the world, where the U.S. was doing well with a negative savings rate while Japan had a high savings rate but was stagnating economically; and that large inflows of foreign capital could have disruptive currency effects which had to be taken into account in discussions of plans for external loans and related financing arrangements. Mr. Hare, responding, said among other things that the question of what was the driving force for creating institutions was a difficult and contentious matter; private agents of course could press Governments for laws, regulations and mechanisms, and States could look at situations in other countries and decide they needed similar institutions, and of course lobbies -- not necessarily well-motivated ones -- could play a role. He would think about the matter in the course of revising his paper. "Moderate" competition also was hard to define, but some balance had to be struck because too much competition did not allow innovation to thrive, especially in its delicate early stages, while too little made established enterprises feel too safe and stifled the advantages of healthy market rivalry. He did not mean to say, in pushing for greater domestic investment and saving, that the role of domestic consumption should be underplayed; he merely favoured a sharp increase in domestic investment, which he considered essential.

It was meanwhile correct, as several speakers had said, that the problem in a number of countries wasn't the absence of institutions but the incorrect functioning of existing institutions, Mr. Hare said. In arguing for new institutions he was perhaps saying the same thing, since the existing institutions were often so drastically different from what they were supposed to be that reforming them amounted to creating something new. Steps to eliminate corruption were vital; and while an entire State administration couldn't be dismantled and rebuilt overnight to reduce opportunities for corruption, measures could be taken quickly in some areas to send a signal that such behaviour would no longer be accepted while more thorough reforms were more slowly carried out.

 

 

        For further information please contact:

Economic Analysis Division
United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE)
Palais des Nations
CH - 1211 Geneva 10, Switzerland

Tel: (+41 22) 917 27 78
Fax: (+41 22) 917 03 09
E-mail:
[email protected]

Website: http://www.unece.org/ead/ead_h.htm

 

 

 Ref: ECE/GEN/01/13